版權說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權,請進行舉報或認領
文檔簡介
1、<p> 1600單詞,9400英文字符,2820漢字</p><p> 本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯</p><p> 外文題目: Estimating the Export and Import Demand for Manufactured Goods: The Role of FDI page:1-2 4-7 </p><p&
2、gt; 出 處: Review of World Economics </p><p> 作 者: Mariam Camarero and Cecilio Tamarit </p><p><b> 英 文:</b></p><p> Estimat
3、ing the Export and Import Demand forManufactured Goods: The Role of FDI</p><p> Mariam Camarero and Cecilio Tamarit</p><p> Abstract: In this paper we estimate the demand for exports and impo
4、rts of manufactured goods for a panel containing the majority of the EU countries as well as the United States and Japan. The model includes as explanatory factors both the traditional determinants of trade and also the
5、stock of foreign direct investment (FDI). We apply panel unit root and cointegration tests allowing for heterogeneity. Whereas there is no evidence of cointegration when using just the traditional formulation, the</p&
6、gt;<p> Keywords: Export and import demand; New Trade Theory; panel data; cointegration; foreign direct investment; </p><p> 1 Introduction</p><p> The demand for exports (or imports)
7、has been traditionally specified as a function of a country’s competitiveness and a foreign (domestic) activity variable. Although this approach has been predominant in the empirical literature, it has remained controver
8、sial. Econometric work with data for different countries spanning a number of years faces some daunting challenges: country- and time-specific effects, endogeneity of the explanatory variables, omission of relevant varia
9、bles, parameter instabil</p><p> Consequently, recent empirical studies have introduced new features both from a theoretical and a methodological point of view. In this paper, we aim to make a contribution
10、to the empirical discussion of long-run relationships for export and import demand. For this purpose, we first estimate the traditiond specification to reproduce some of the existing results in the literature, but using
11、a new econometric framework for the analysis. In particular, we apply recent panel cointegration techniques</p><p> The paper is organized hereafter as follows. In Section 2, we review the theoretical issue
12、s relating trade to its determinants, and more specifically, the role of FDI. In Section 3, we discuss the empirical results for a panel formed by 11 European countries, the United States, and Japan. Section 4 makes some
13、 concluding remarks and outlines possible directions for future research.</p><p> 2 Theoretical Considerations: Trade versus FDI?</p><p> The increasing openness of the capital markets in Euro
14、pe as a result of the Single Market initiative, as well as the process of globalization at the world level, has renewed the interest of both the theoretical and the applied literature in the study of the effects of inter
15、national mobility of production factors on trade. Similarly, many developing countries have embarked themselves on a process of liberalization during the 1990s giving rise to many uncertainties concerning macroeconomic a
16、nd mon</p><p> However, the accumulation of evidence from at least the last twenty years suggests that it is important to examine in depth the sign of the relationship linking trade and FDI, since the relat
17、ionship is heavily influenced by the activity of multinational corporations (MNCs). Consequently, any theoretical treatment that sees FDI as similar to portfolio or physical factor allocation can be misleading and from t
18、he 1970s there have been various attempts to shed light on the relationship between trade</p><p> Classical View: The Standard Trade Theory (1950s—1960s)</p><p> Under the traditional Hecksche
19、r-Ohlin framework (H-O), provided that a certain set of restrictive assumptions holds)1 either international trade or international mobility of factors of production could equalize factor prices across countries. The con
20、ventional view of the relationship between factor movements and commodity trade maintains that the two are (Mundell 1957). However, the assumptions of the factor price equalization theorem can never be fully met in reali
21、ty, so that factor movements c</p><p> Theory of Industrial Organization and the Key Concepts of Economic Integration of Products and Factors (1970s-1980s)</p><p> It is commonly acknowledged
22、that MNCs are involved in a substantial part of international trade and capital movements. MNCs are characterized by setting up businesses and producing commodities outside their home country. The movement of capital whi
23、ch takes place in this context, and which consists of establishing foreign affiliates or acquiring majority share positions in existing foreign companies, is considered direct investment.</p><p> A company
24、that is setting up production abroad has to compare its disadvantages (communication costs, differences in culture, language, legislation, exchange and sovereign risks) to the alternatives like exporting or licensing.<
25、;/p><p> Dunning (1972, 1977) formulated an eclectic view of the different approaches made by the theory of industrial organization, which gave birth to the so-called OLI paradigm. According to it> a firm’s
26、 choice between the three alternatives (exporting, licensing, or investing abroad) depends on the combination of the three following advantages: ownership-specific advantages, locational advantages, and internalization a
27、dvantages in the target market.</p><p> An issue of interest when the analysis is focused on European countries is the effect that integration has on inward and outward FDI, both within and between blocs. T
28、he evolution of FDI and its expected complementary or substitute effects on trade would also depend on the reasons that justified the investment decision before the process of integration started and also on the changes
29、in the market structure as well as the trade policy measures boosted by the integration process.2 Due to the compl</p><p> New Trade Theory and New Economic Geography (1980s-1990s)</p><p> The
30、 early attempts to reconcile the theory of multinationals with trade theory appears in Markusen (1984) and Helpman (1984). The former focused on horizontal investments in which a firm sets up abroad to produce the same p
31、roduct that it produces at home, while the latter focused on vertical investments in which the production process is decomposed by stages according to factor intensities in different countries. In both cases, multination
32、als export services produced from physical factors, rathe</p><p> -Vertical integration (a la Helpman) is based on different factor endowments and, therefore is an efficiency-seeking FDI that may have mainl
33、y a complementary relationship with trade.</p><p> -Horizontal integration (a la Markusen or a la Brainard) is mainly based on the improvement of market access or market growth prospects, thus generating a
34、market-seeking FDI that will have a substitutional relationship with trade.</p><p> The literature on MNCs normally distinguishes between vertical and horizontal firms, and suggests that the latter's lo
35、cation decisions are determined mainly by market access rather than by cost considerations. However, Neary (2002) shows that even when multinational activity is purely horizontal, yet costs are crucial in determining whe
36、re in the union a new plant will locate.</p><p> When the sum of the fixed costs at the firm level and the tariffs are higher than the fixed costs at the plant level, the multiplant production is more appro
37、priate than a centralized one. In these models of horizontal multiplant production, the decision to engage in multinational production reflects a trade-off between the firm’s desire to be close to foreign markets (becaus
38、e of trade costs) and the desire to concentrate production at home and exploit economies of scale (home market effect^),</p><p> A unified approach has been developed recently aiming at endogenizing multina
39、tional firms in general-equilibrium trade models and integrating separate contributions on multiplant horizontal MNCs with work on vertical ones.</p><p> The results show that vertical multinationals domina
40、te when countries are very different in relative factor endowments and, conversely, horizontal multinationals dominate when the countries are similar in size and in relative endowments, and trade costs are moderate to hi
41、gh. Although, generally, vertical direct investment could be thought of as expanding north-south (big-small countries) trade and horizontal as associated with decreasing trade in north-north (or equal size) relationships
42、 between</p><p> The possibility of splitting the production process into different stages and/or the existence of multiproduct firms gives rise to situations in which, regardless of the aims of the firms,
43、the most feasible outcome is a positive relationship between an increase in MNCs activities and trade, either intrafirm and/or intraindustrial (Baldwin and Ottaviano 2001 and Markusen and Maskus 2001).</p><p&g
44、t;<b> 譯 文:</b></p><p> 制成品出口和進口需求的評估:外商直接投資的作用摘要</p><p> 在本文中,我們對一組包括大多數(shù)歐盟成員國、美國、以及日本的國家的制成品進出口需求面板數(shù)據(jù)進行估計。除了傳統(tǒng)意義上影響貿(mào)易的因素,該模型的解釋變量還包括外國直接投資(FDI)??紤]到異方差的可能,我們運用了群體單位根檢驗和協(xié)整測試。但是對傳統(tǒng)
45、公式進行協(xié)整測試的結(jié)果并無問題,結(jié)果顯示增廣模型的變量長期相關。另外,回歸結(jié)果只要指出了貿(mào)易與FDI之間的關系。</p><p> 關鍵詞:出口和進口需求;新貿(mào)易理論;面板數(shù)據(jù);協(xié)整;外商直接投資;</p><p><b> 簡介</b></p><p> 進出口的需求在傳統(tǒng)意義上是一個國家的競爭力及其對外(或本國)經(jīng)濟活力的體現(xiàn)。盡管在
46、實證中常常得到青睞,但是關于此方法的爭議一直存在。針對不同國家橫跨數(shù)年的數(shù)據(jù)計量工作面臨著一些嚴峻的挑戰(zhàn):國別因素和歷史因素的影響、解釋變量的內(nèi)生關系、有關變量的遺漏、以及非定常數(shù)據(jù)參數(shù)的非平穩(wěn)(1998年Hooper等人)。同時,根據(jù)深受產(chǎn)業(yè)組織理論影響的所謂新貿(mào)易理論,更多可能影響進出口的因素已開始受到關注,比如說外國直接投資(FDI)或是貿(mào)易產(chǎn)品的質(zhì)量等等。</p><p> 因此,最近的實證研究同時從理
47、論和方法論出發(fā)提出了新的觀點。我們希望本文能對進出口需求長期關系的實證研究提供一定參考。為此,我們首先運用新穎的計量方法對文獻中已有的研究結(jié)果進行了回顧。特別地,我們運用結(jié)合了時間序列和截面數(shù)據(jù)的協(xié)整方法,對經(jīng)濟變量中經(jīng)常出現(xiàn)的非平穩(wěn)和內(nèi)生性問題進行了處理。此外,通過同樣的計量方法,我們還根據(jù)近期的理論工作進行了相應的擴展,由此檢測了經(jīng)濟的穩(wěn)定性。通過對傳統(tǒng)解釋變量和FDI存量的運用,我們將特別關注針對一組經(jīng)濟合作與發(fā)展組織(OECD)
48、成員國制成品進出口需求的估計。</p><p> 本文旨在為貿(mào)易和FDI的長期關系提供新的觀點。下文的結(jié)構(gòu)如下:在第二部分中,我們將回顧有關貿(mào)易及其影響因素的理論問題,特別地,我們將關注FDI的作用。第三部分中,我們將討論針對由十一個歐洲國家、美國、以及日本組成的面板數(shù)據(jù)實證結(jié)果。第四部分包括總結(jié)評論,并會概括未來研究的可能方向。</p><p> 2 從理論出發(fā):貿(mào)易還是FDI?&l
49、t;/p><p> 在歐洲單一市場和世界范圍全球化的驅(qū)動下,歐洲資本市場日趨開放,并由此帶動了對生產(chǎn)要素國際流動影響的理論和實證研究。類似的,由于宏觀經(jīng)濟和財政狀況日益失穩(wěn),貿(mào)易和長期直接投資也不容樂觀,一些發(fā)展中國家自上世紀九十年代開始了開放市場的進程。不幸的是,根據(jù)Markusen (1997)的觀點,貿(mào)易經(jīng)濟學家至今尚未合理而深入地解決長期直接投資的問題,而貿(mào)易理論的范式受到Mundell (1957)的開創(chuàng)
50、性論文的影響;根據(jù)Mundell的觀點,商品貿(mào)易和生產(chǎn)要素是互可替代的。</p><p> 然而,過去二十年間的實證數(shù)據(jù)表明,深入研究貿(mào)易和FDI之間的長期關系是絕對有必要的,因為二者之間的關系深受跨國公司(MNCs)經(jīng)營活動的影響。因此,如果有理論方法的出發(fā)點是FDI與證券投資組合或有形生產(chǎn)要素分配類似,那么這一理論將會是誤導性的。自上世紀七十年代以來,已有多方面的研究旨在揭示貿(mào)易與FDI之間的關系。<
51、/p><p> 標準貿(mào)易理論(二十世紀五十年代到二十世紀六十年代)</p><p> 傳統(tǒng)的赫克歇爾-俄林(H-O)定理提出了一系列限制條件,不論是國際貿(mào)易還是生產(chǎn)要素的國際流動,都不能夠與國與國之間的要素價格相提并論。習慣上認為,要素流動和商品貿(mào)易之間的關系仍是替代品(Mundell 1957)。然而,因素價格均衡定理的假說永遠得不到現(xiàn)實的驗證,因此要素流動并不能保證商品或是要素價格的均
52、衡。事實上,Markusen (1983)主張,商品和要素流動之間的替代關系是例外而不是定理,但是二者之間的互補性在很多情況下卻是存在的。</p><p> 產(chǎn)業(yè)組織理論和產(chǎn)品與要素經(jīng)濟一體化的核心思想(二十世紀七十年代到二十世紀八十年代)</p><p> 跨國企業(yè)通常被認為是國際貿(mào)易和資本流動的重要參與者。跨國企業(yè)的特點是在本國以外開展生意和生產(chǎn)商品。在此情況下的資本流動,及其涉及
53、的建立國外分支機構(gòu)以及從現(xiàn)存外國公司獲得多數(shù)股權的問題,都涵蓋在直接投資的范疇里。公司必須考慮,相對于出口或特許經(jīng)營,在國外生產(chǎn)是否存在(通訊費用,以及文化、語言、法律、交六和主權風險不同等方面的)劣勢。</p><p> 從產(chǎn)業(yè)組織理論的不同研究方法出發(fā),Dunning (1972, 1977)提出了一個折衷主義的觀點,OLI范式也由此產(chǎn)生。根據(jù)此范式,在出口、特許經(jīng)營、還是外國投資之間,公司的選擇取決于一下
54、三種優(yōu)勢的組合:特有的所有權優(yōu)勢、本地優(yōu)勢、以及目標市場的內(nèi)在優(yōu)勢。分析歐洲國家時往往會遇到這樣一個有趣的問題,即一體化對FDI的雙向流通,以及集團內(nèi)部和集團之間的直接投資,都有一定的影響。FDI的演變及其對貿(mào)易預期的補充或替代作用,也取決于一體化進程開始之前,影響最終投資決定的那些因素??紤]到這些關系的復雜性,一個一般均衡模型足以包含所有這些因素間的相互作用。但是,上世紀八十年代,基于Brander和Spencer的相互傾銷模型,另一
55、種觀點采用寡頭壟斷的行業(yè)部分均衡模型形式形成了。</p><p> 新貿(mào)易理論和新經(jīng)濟地理學(二十世紀八十年代到二十世紀九十年代)</p><p> Markusen (1984) and Helpman (1984)提出的,調(diào)解跨國公司理論和貿(mào)易理論的最早嘗試??鐕纠碚撝赜谒酵顿Y,即公司在國外生產(chǎn)于其在國內(nèi)相同的產(chǎn)品;貿(mào)易理論著重于垂直投資,即根據(jù)不同國家的要素稟賦將生產(chǎn)過程
56、分解成各個階段。相同的是,在兩種情況下跨國公司都是加工實物要素,而非利用自身的要素或在此基礎上加工實物要素。對(無形)資產(chǎn)所有權的開發(fā)利用促進了在水平或垂直方向上分段結(jié)構(gòu)的跨國企業(yè)的發(fā)展,并證實了FDI和貿(mào)易之間的互補和替代關系。</p><p> 垂直一體化 (a la Helpman)的基礎是不同的要素稟賦,因此可能是與貿(mào)易主要存在互補關系的、追求效率的FDI。</p><p>
57、水平一體化(a la Markusen 或者 a la Brainard)主要基于市場準入的改善或者市場成長前景,因此催生了尋求市場機會的FDI,而這種FDI主要與貿(mào)易存在替代關系。</p><p> 研究跨國企業(yè)的文獻通常將水平和垂直一體化加以區(qū)分,并且認為后者的地理位置選擇主要是由市場準入而非成本考慮決定的。然而,Neary (2002)揭示說即使跨國企業(yè)經(jīng)營活動完全在垂直水平上進行,成本仍是決定新工廠選址
58、何處的重要考慮。當企業(yè)水平上的固定成本和關稅總和高于工廠水平的固定成本,分散于多個工廠的生產(chǎn)比集中生產(chǎn)更為合適。在垂直多工廠生產(chǎn)的模型中,參與跨國生產(chǎn)的決策反映了企業(yè)進入外國市場的愿望(出于貿(mào)易成本的考慮)與企業(yè)集中在母國生產(chǎn)以達到規(guī)模經(jīng)濟愿望之間(母國市場效應)的權衡。最近,針對一般均衡下跨國企業(yè)貿(mào)易模型和垂直多工廠跨國企業(yè)一體化效應的研究,提出了一個綜合性的方法。研究結(jié)果顯示,當不同國家之間的相應要素稟賦差別很大時,垂直結(jié)構(gòu)的跨國企
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預覽,若沒有圖紙預覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負責。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權或不適當內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 制成品出口和進口需求的評估外商直接投資的作用【外文翻譯】
- 外國直接投資(fdi)的作用制成品進出口需求估計【外文翻譯】
- 外國直接投資(fdi)的作用制成品進出口需求估計【外文翻譯】
- 外商直接投資對浙江省工業(yè)制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)的影響分析 [文獻綜述]
- 外商直接投資對浙江省工業(yè)制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)的影響分析【開題報告】
- 外商直接投資對浙江省工業(yè)制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)的影響分析【畢業(yè)論文】
- 外商直接投資對浙江省工業(yè)制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)的影響分析【任務書】
- 外文翻譯--泰國的外商直接投資和出口績效(節(jié)選)
- 外文翻譯--外商直接投資和出口—基于越南的經(jīng)驗 (節(jié)選)
- 外文翻譯--墨西哥的外商直接投資和進出口 (節(jié)選)
- 印度的制成品出口比較結(jié)構(gòu)與展望【外文翻譯】
- 泰國的外商直接投資和出口績效【外文翻譯】
- 談我國工業(yè)制成品出口現(xiàn)狀
- 墨西哥的外商直接投資和進出口【外文翻譯】
- 外商直接投資和出口—基于越南的經(jīng)驗【外文翻譯】
- 外商直接投資對浙江省工業(yè)制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)的影響分析【畢業(yè)論文+文獻綜述+開題報告+任務書】
- 外文翻譯--外商直接投資是如何影響加納企業(yè)的出口決策?(節(jié)選)
- 中國制成品出口結(jié)構(gòu)優(yōu)化研究.pdf
- 我國工業(yè)制成品出口狀況分析.pdf
- 外文翻譯--外商直接投資怎樣影響經(jīng)濟的增長(節(jié)選)
評論
0/150
提交評論